1

Capitalism is bad at fiscal and monetary policy

Capitalism is bad at fiscal policy. Capitalism is also bad at monetary policy but that’s less apparent. You cannot hear a loud hum but you can hear a small bang.

 

I often wonder how effective central bank policy is at maintaining economic stability and price stability. Unfortunately I cannot observe comparable economies of size and complexity which do not have central banks actively managing inflation. Central banks who do not target inflation by and large manage dirty floats which import developed world monetary policy often to address mismatched sets of problems.

Perhaps it is a good idea for policy to be active only when price changes falls outside accepted bands, say +8% inflation to -3% deflation. Perhaps policy has no impact when price changes are within the range 0 to 5%. Perhaps policy is not necessary in the neighbourhood of this range. This is speculation that is hard to test.

The money multiplier measures the ability of the fractional reserve banking system to take a buck of real money and turn it into 8 or 9 bucks of … real money. Central banks control over this multiplier is via a required reserve ratio. It tells banks how much of each buck of cash deposit they can lend out. If the ratio is X, then the multiplier is 1/X. The proof is simple. Bank 1 lends out X which is deposited in bank 2 which can lend out X^2 and so on. The sum of this series is 1/X in the limit. But here is the problem that we face today. It requires that for every 1 buck, there is X bucks demand for credit. The appetite for credit just isn’t very robust. Companies have just come out of an acute recession. Individuals have been over levered and over spending and now need to save. If the savings rate is increasing, the marginal propensity to consume must be falling and demand for personal credit must be falling. Even as central banks are expanding their balance sheets, banks just aren’t. The actual money multiplier is shrinking.

The pessimist is worried that monetary policy is not working and that the disconnect between M0 and M2 is storing up future inflationary pressures of dangerous proportions. The optimist is happy that the printing of money has not had immediate inflationary effects and that households have increased their savings rates as they should to address the imbalances between East and West that had built up to the crisis of 2008. These, however, are the dynamics of household credit. What about corporate credit?

A low interest rate presents a low hurdle rate for investment. Corporate demand for credit will be dependent on product demand which is dependent on domestic and export demand. Domestic demand is a function of household propensity to consume. Export demand is dependent on a whole bunch of exogenous factors. It is sensitive to the terms of trade and thus exchange rate and inflation. As global growth recovers from the recession of 2008 and it becomes apparent that growth either is less robust than expected or less robust than necessary for tax receipts to pay down public debt, desperation often leads to beggar-thy-neighbour exports policies.

On the consumption side, one of the imbalances leading up to the crisis was a negative savings rate of the US consumer and a generally low savings rate in developed countries. Economists at the time prescribed prudent financial management and raising the savings rate. At the same time, they prescribed lowering savings rates in emerging economies like China as a means of correcting trade imbalances. The credit crisis had an instantaneous effect of reversing the direction of trade imbalances and addressing the domestic savings rates. Faced with lack of credit, US and rich world consumers had no choice but to increase savings rates. In addition, sudden risk aversion and uncertainty over investment portfolios, performance of pensions and employment prospects helped to raise savings rates. This manifests in a reduced marginal propensity to consume. What is individually rational collectively self defeating and detrimental to aggregate demand in what is known as the paradox of thrift. The paradox of thrift has several well known counterarguments.

–          Slack demand leads to lower prices spurring demand.

–          Savings are loanable funds representing an increase in potential lending. Consumer spending is offset by institutional lending.

–          Assumes a closed economy. Savings may be invested abroad.

The problem faced today is that:

–          Quantitative easing is balancing deflationary pressures. Moreover, price inflation is more prevalent in asset prices (claims on future goods) than in goods (current goods).

–          Savings are loanable but its not just individuals who are hoarding money, institutions are hoarding money as well, as evidenced by the reduced multiplier. The expansion of central bank balance sheets has not found an analogous or proportional expansion of commercial bank balance sheets.

–          The paradox of thrift actually holds for closed systems and the World is a closed system. In addition, trying to break the paradox at the domestic level leads to a beggar thy neighbour approach towards trade policy.

So the paradox of thrift is a real issue and likely to mean weaker real growth and less inflationary pressure.

In emerging markets, a larger proportion of income is spent on subsistence hence the marginal propensity to consume is not only higher but more stable. In more mature economies where incomes are higher, the proportion of income spent on subsistence is lower and thus the marginal propensity to consume is less stable. As government spending seeks to fill the deficiency, the transmission mechanism, the velocity of money, is a function of the marginal propensity to consume. Much as the fractional reserve system of banking has a multiplier, fiscal policy passes through a spending multiplier. That multiplier has in the current economic climate, been reduced. Where once government spending was multiplied, today it is being saved. Why? Because we can. Because greater uncertainty encourages more saving. Because the reaction to more inflation may perversely encourage cash hoarding. Because people make strategic errors. The result is a realization of the paradox of thrift at a global level.

The loss of the multiplier is not catastrophic as long as it is not counted on. It is therefore crucial that Government therefore directs its fiscal efforts at productive expenditure. If a road is built, it should be a toll road and a profitable one. If a railway needs to be built it has to be a profitable project. Bridges to nowhere lead to nowhere physically and fiscally.

Time is necessary for savings and consumption rates to stabilize and to reflect income and employment prospects and inflation expectations. It takes time for businesses to stabilize their demand for credit, for lenders to stabilize their risk aversion, for the banking system’s multiplier to re-establish itself. In the meantime there is little that capitalist systems can do to steer an economy in the path they wish.

For centrally planned economies the problem is not easy but it is easier. They have better short term control over the path of development of the economy, but over the longer term are hostage to the same noise and uncertainty, perhaps more so, than their capitalist counterparts.




Hedge Fund Investing In A Post 2008 World

Investing is not for the faint of heart. Neither is it for the psychotic risk taker. Investing requires balance, rationality and a good deal of detached and independent thinking. So don’t listen to me. Figure it out for yourselves. Here are a few common declarations by investors and a few (loaded) questions they should ask.

We will only invest with managers who did well through 2008. Did 2008 represent normal conditions? What is the probability that the liquidity conditions of 2008 repeat themselves? How does one manage around this probability? What is the opportunity cost of assuming a high probability say > 20%?

We will never invest with any manager who suspended or (gated) restricted redemptions in 2008. Would it have been preferable to have a firesale, or an orderly liquidation? Would it have been fair to all investors both those who want out and those who want to remain invested? Was the manager protecting their own franchise or exercising due care in discharging their fiduciary duties?

We were surprised and disappointed at the behaviour of the manager in 2008. Did one understand what the manager was doing prior to crisis? Leading into the crisis? Did one understand what the manager was facing in the midst of the crisis? Coming out of the crisis? To the extent that one is comfortable investing in distress investing funds, does one see some parallels between gating and suspension and the Chapter 11 reorganization process?

We will only invest with liquid funds. Does one need the liquidity? If the only time one needs the liquidity is in a crisis then is seeking partially liquid investments which end up illiquid in a crisis the right strategy? An illiquid strategy or portfolio offering liquid fund terms is usually a failure of asset liability management, but how about a liquid strategy or portfolio with less liquid fund terms? Is it fair for a manager to demand some level of stability of assets for business stability reasons?

We will only invest with managers who have a long and consistent track record. How does one differentiate between skill and luck? Track records are the result of the combination of skill and luck. How many teaspoons of skill were added to how many thimblefuls of luck? See my coin tossing experiment.

We will only invest with managers with a record of making money on the short side. We will not invest with managers who use futures to short. Does it matter how the pasta is made if it is healthy, non toxic, hygienically prepared and tastes good? Or perhaps the diner would like to take a turn as cook?

We will never invest in managers who are short volatility. Is a short volatility portfolio always vulnerable to tail risk?

We always want the manager to have substantially all of his liquid net worth in the fund. Would you put substantially all of your net worth in your portfolio of hedge funds? Is such a manager diversifying their own personal portfolio sufficiently? What does this say about the risk aversion of the manager, their confidence in themselves and their propensity to take risk in the fund?

We will not invest in highly levered funds. In fixed income arbitrage, what level of leverage is acceptable and what is typical? In a futures based portfolio, how do you define leverage? What does margin to equity tell you about sensitivity of the NAV to fluctuations in the underlying markets?

We like to invest in market neutral funds. What market is the portfolio and the underlying positions neutral to? In credit for example, is the spread neutrality matched across the term structure?

We seek a fund with percentage of winning months over 90%, volatility below 3%, average returns of 11-12%, drawdown of no more than 1%, an 18 year track record, assets under management of several billion USD, monthly liquidity and fees of 1 and 20. Does one require an independent custodian and administrator? Does the fund sound familiar?

Investors are still adjusting from the shock of 2008 and the shock of 2009. It will take time. In the meantime, the measure of rationality in the world remains constrained. While it remains so, there are still obvious opportunities.




Sovereign Debt Investing: A Distress Investing Approach

The credit quality of sovereign debt is the subject of current scrutiny and debate.
The business of government is a complex one with multiple objectives and indeed philosophies.
Some believe that governments are inherently inefficient and therefore should have their mandate clearly defined and limited. Others see government as an arbiter that corrects market imperfections.

Unable to deal with such complexities, I have decided to look at how government fund’s itself and the implications arising. I have also decided to take an even narrower view, that of an investor in sovereign debt. What would I look for, what would I demand and what would I avoid?

I would like the issuer to be solvent. Given that governments can print money, I am less worried about default, however, I do worry about the debasing of the issuer’s currency (the FX rate) and the erosion of purchasing power (inflation.)

I would like the issuer to be profitable. This needs clarification. Governments derive profits from two sources, profits from investments and enterprise, and tax revenue. I would like to see the issuer’s economy in a state of healthy growth as this is positive for tax revenue. I am a firm believer that tax revenue is highly elastic and therefore would subscribe to having a lower tax rate and higher economic growth than a higher tax rate and lower economic growth. I would prefer that a government derives a significant proportion of revenues from investment and enterprise. There is a substantial risk that this can crowd out private enterprise. A sovereign wealth fund with a good deal of independence is a helpful vehicle towards this end. Governments should be investors and not operators of enterprise. They are simply poor allocators of resources and lousy businesspeople. A segregation of the investment decision is important.

Government must be a going concern. If we assume that governments do not create wealth from resource reallocation, the only creation of wealth and cash flow must come from ongoing operations. A separate analysis of the available assets for sale of a government including non income yielding assets should be done but a government can only sell so much of the family silver before it decimates its assets. A sovereign wealth fund can, however, engage in acquisitions and divestitures, hopefully on a profitable basis. They often do that by investing in private equity directly or through funds. Land sales, licensing and other rent extraction are other ways of raising cash. I would be wary of governments who raise cash this way as it either reduces its stock of potentially productive assets or is simply ad hoc taxation and is sometimes a sign of desperation.

I would like to see a government with a good handle on its operational expenses. This is a complicated concept. What are the operational expenses of government? Provision of law and order, state sponsored healthcare, social security, public education, are examples of operational expenses. We discuss capex separately as it is an investment despite being a negative cash flow. A judgment needs to be made whether a public service is provided efficiently or not. A service may be efficiently provided yet represent a substantial operational expense if the service provided is of a high quality or value. The decision to provide such service is a democratic decision and not a commercial one. As a creditor I would like to see efficient execution of the non-commercial decision. The execution of the establishment and operation of the business should be done on a commercial basis. Government can and will in all probability have to subsidize the service but should do so at arms length in such a way that it interferes as little as possible with commercial pricing and allocation within that market.

From the above, I would seek to arrive at the equivalent measure of an EBITDA of a government. Note that taxation is a source of revenue for government. All the usual adjustments should be made to handle capitalization of leases, adjustment of depreciation for the true and economic cost of maintaining capital for use as a going concern. The Enterprise Value of government needs to be estimated. I will not go into more detail here as it would be an entire body of work. The idea is to arrive at some comparable valuation for the sovereign issuer. Valuation should be made on a going concern basis as well as a liquidation basis even though it is inconceivable that a government would file for Chapter 7 or Chapter 11 liquidation. While not 100% relevant, the exercise would draw one’s attention to off balance sheet liabilities, intercreditor guarantees, and the complex capital and legal structure of the issuer.

Ultimately, any good or service has to be paid for wherever it is provided by the private sector or by government. The role of government is to redistribute cost and wealth through taxes and the socialization of certain goods and services. Then there is the cost of that redistribution. As a creditor I would like to see an efficient redistribution from a cost perspective. Efficient redistribution from a welfare perspective is something best left to academics.

Theoretically, and in some senses practically, governments have a distinct advantage over private enterprise in raising debt capital. We see this in the yield on government debt relative to private enterprise debt. Unless government are fraudulent, grossly incompetent or simply act in bad faith, capital markets are open to them. The question is at what price. Governments financial planning therefore needs to centre on profitability and not cash flow (unless fraudulent, grossly incompetent or dastardly).

It seems therefore that as long as governments are run reasonably poorly, but not unreasonably poorly like some clearly are, debt capital markets are open to them and its a matter of price.

As I said in the beginning, default in the sovereign currency is not an issue. The issue is exchange rate and inflation. The higher is inflation expected to be, the higher the yield a creditor will demand for compensation. Anything that threatens the stability of that expectation, even to the downside, will increase the yield in the form of an option premium over base compensation. Government’s inflation fighting abilities therefore impact pricing. Now FX. If the exchange rate is expected to deteriorate, the external investor or creditor will demand a compensatory premium. Any attempts to hedge currency is likely to be self defeating or duration mismatched.

Arbitrage investors in sovereign bonds do so on the basis of no default, technical implications for inflation expectations priced in the TIPS market, technical no arbitrage conditions in the swaps and repo markets, liquidity premia in on and off the runs and in the convexity of the term structure.

Long term liability based investors invest in sovereign bonds based on a macro view, on the fundamental economic strength of the underlying economies.

The above is a distress investors’ point of view of analysing the investment proposition in sovereign debt. No one approach is right but understanding all approaches, understanding which constituents are the marginal driver of pricing, can lead to interesting investment opportunities.

 

 




Why Equity Markets Are Weak

Its not fundamentals that are driving equity markets and responsible for the current weakness. Fundamentals were bound to weaken once the first round of inventory restocking had taken place and the benefits of cost cutting had been realized.

 The world economy is still weak, but in a recovery phase, and conditions have returned to normal, albeit at depressed levels.

What is driving equity markets lower is tightening of monetary conditions as central banks across the world try to normalize policy after a period of unprecedented monetary stimulus.

India and China have increased their reserve ratios, the Aussies have raised rates, even the Fed is slowing its pace of mortgage asset purchases.




US Indebtedness

Debt levels as a percentage of GDP: